A service of the

Download article as PDF

In the course of transition from planned economies to market economies, foreign direct investment played an important role and contributed to international economic integration in Central and Eastern Europe. This paper investigates the determinants of FDI in Central and Eastern Europe, a region which in large part still lacks strong institutions. The empirical analysis presented in this article finds evidence that country default risk is not necessarily a hindrance to FDI. In contrast, factors like market size, labour cost and trade liberalisation do matter for FDI engagement in the region.

Foreign direct investment (FDI) has long been regarded as a catalyst for restructuring, modernisation and economic development in Central and East European countries (CEECs), so-called transition economies.1 From a macroeconomic perspective, it seems to be the case that FDI facilitated the transition from planned to market economies in CEECs and their integration into the world economy.2 After the breakdown of socialism, foreign investors, mainly from Western Europe and other high-income countries, found it attractive to establish subsidiaries or to acquire production plants in CEECs.3

As shown in Figure 1, the stock of FDI in CEECs4 from high-income economies5 has increased strongly since the early 1990s. Yearly FDI inflows to CEECs have increased almost constantly, only experiencing a heavy decline due to the global economic crisis in 2008-2009. Since then, the yearly FDI inflows have not reached their pre-crisis peak of 2007.

Figure 1
FDI inward stock and flow in Central and East European countries, 1994-2013
in billions of euros
29876.png

Note: Central and East European countries: Albania, Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Croatia, Hungary, Lithuania, Latvia, Poland, Romania, the Russian Federation, the Slovak Republic, Slovenia, Ukraine, Source countries: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, the United States.

Source: Authors’ elaboration on data from wiiw FDI Database.

FDI in CEECs has been concentrated mostly in a few economies, namely Hungary, Poland and the Czech Republic, which together accounted for 48 per cent of total FDI stock in the region in 2013. Both, the geographical proximity to Western Europe and EU enlargement, with its institutional unification in many economic areas, are two major reasons for the concentration of FDI in these countries.6

Because of positive expectations about the developmental effects of FDI, many countries introduced policies to attract FDI, such as tax holidays, import duty exemptions, direct subsidies to foreign firms, infrastructure improvements and sometimes even monopoly rights.7 These policies contribute to an investor-friendly business environment, which is essential for sustainable and long-term oriented investment. Policy schemes are, however, only one attraction factor for FDI in CEECs. There are more traditional factors, such as market size, proximity and integration into the world economy.8 Last but not least, recent literature on institutional factors shows that stable and reliable institutions matter strongly for the attraction of FDI into CEECs.9 While every investment bears risk, foreign investment is even more vulnerable because of uncertainties related to distance, familiarity with the local environment and possible changes to formal and informal institutions. Recent economic developments in Eastern Europe related to the geopolitical tensions between Russia, Ukraine and the EU have renewed the importance of a stable business environment for trade and FDI.

In this paper, we pay attention to traditional explanatory factors of FDI in CEECs as well as risk (in terms of institutional factors) as a determinant of FDI from high-income countries to CEECs. A simple correlation analysis between creditworthiness (as an important component of risk) and FDI shows that the correlation coefficient is positive and significant. Beyond purely descriptive analyses, we also make use of a newly established panel database on bilateral FDI flows from 17 individual source countries to 14 CEECs between 1994 and 2013. We assume that gravity effects between the two groups of countries play a role. Furthermore, we expect that higher risk associated with weaker institutions also matters for the attraction of FDI.

Theoretical considerations and hypotheses

In international business literature, one of the most important theoretical concepts to explain multinational companies’ activities is the ownership, location and internalisation (OLI) paradigm.10 The existing literature translates the theoretical considerations into a number of explanatory variables,11 and a new stream of literature on FDI seeks to incorporate OLI advantages into general equilibrium models12 and into a general gravity model.13

The market size of source and host economies is an important proxy for product demand and potential growth. Artige and Nicolini claim that the market size measured by GDP has the highest explanatory power of FDI per capita.14 Charkrabarti argues that according to the market size hypothesis, a large market is necessary for the exploitation of economies of scale.15 In other words, once the market size reaches a critical value, its further growth leads to FDI increases. Thanks to the great popularity of this hypothesis, the market size of the host economy is taken into account in most econometric studies on the determinants of FDI.16 Therefore, we hypothesise that, firstly, the larger the market of a CEEC the more attractive it is for foreigners to invest there and that, secondly, the larger the source economy the larger the FDI flows that these countries direct to CEECs (market size hypothesis).

Further, we assume that there is a relationship between trade and FDI.17 Normally, we expect that trade openness has a positive impact on FDI because a liberal trade regime of the host economy facilitates import and export activity of investing firms. Accordingly, various analyses record a strongly positive effect of openness on FDI.18 Thus, we expect that a country’s degree of trade openness has a positive influence on FDI inflows.

Labour costs have been frequently discussed as a determinant of FDI.19 Some studies show that it is skills and not wages that have an impact on FDI location.20 At the same time, many investigations demonstrate that higher wages discourage FDI.21 In line with this latter literature, we assume that lower labour costs in CEECs attract FDI from developed economies.

In the international business literature, the concept of distance is associated not only with its geographical dimension but also with cultural and linguistic factors. Distance can be considered as a measure of the transaction costs of FDI activities.22 Prior research demonstrates a negative impact of distance on FDI.23 Thus, we assume that a growing distance between source and host country reduces FDI flows and stocks.

Finally, existing empirical evidence acknowledges the importance of legal transparency, institutional stability as reflected in policies towards FDI, tax incentives, the effectiveness of current regulations, the scope of corruption and the degree of political stability for attracting FDI.24 Loree and Guisinger25 and Henisz26 found a negative relationship between political risk and FDI. In our study, we assume that the better the institutional environment in terms of the creditworthiness of the host country, the more likely it is for this country to attract FDI from developed economies.

Data and empirical specification

The empirical results are based on a sample of time-series cross-sectional data on 14 CEECs obtained from a database by the Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies. Panel data analysis is a popular tool for researching aggregate FDI flows. The first dependent variable (FDIINij) is inward FDI flows (in euros). The other dependent variable, FDIISij, represents FDI inward stock (in euros).

Our dataset covers the years 1994-2013. Each observation point represents either an FDI flow (in million euros) between one of the 17 developed source countries i and a recipient country j or an accumulated stock of previous FDI inflows in the host country in any given year.27 The source countries were selected in accordance with their contributions of FDI outflows to the world. Their FDI outflows in 2012 accounted for more than half of total world FDI outflows (53 per cent). The selected host countries received only a modest share of total world FDI inflows in 2012 (seven per cent), but this represents a strong increase over the early 1990s.

We use a general gravity model, denoting the year by t, source country by i and host country by j, and estimate the following specifications:

FDIINtij = f(GDPti, GDPtj, tradetij, distanceij, ULCtj, risktj)

(1)

FDIIStij = f(GDPti, GDPtj, tradetij, distanceij, ULCtj, risktj),

(2)

where GDPti(j) stands for the size of the source (host) country, ULCtj are the unit labour costs in the host country, tradetij measures the openness of the host economy, distanceij represents the geographical distance, and risktj denotes the legal and institutional framework in the host country.28 Hence, this form of the gravity equation controls for factor cost, openness and institutional development. Since we cannot exclude that FDI reacts to these explanatory variables only with a lag, we estimate Equations (1) and (2) using both non-lagged and one-year lagged independent variables.

Considering our model specification, a relative unitless labour cost variable was used to ensure that a lower wage does not depend on labour productivity or currency valuation. The variable distanceij refers to the geographical distance between the capital cities of country i and country j in kilometres. Multinational firms engaged in export-oriented investments are likely to invest in an economy with established trade relations; hence, the trade variable is designed to capture the openness of the host economy.29 Given our interest in the bilateral FDI flows, the trade variable is also constructed bilaterally. It is calculated as the ratio of total imports by the host country from a certain source country to the host country’s GDP per capita.

As described by Jun and Singh, the riskiness of the economic environment in the host country may discourage investment in catching-up countries.30 Previous studies use different variables to capture this effect, for instance, fluctuations in inflation and economic growth, exchange rate stability,31 and EBRD transition indicators of institutional development.32 A high collinearity of these indicators is a great limitation to their simultaneous use. Therefore, just one particular variable is usually included in a model at a time. Some authors resolve this issue by constructing their own risk indicators using various methods, such as principal components analysis33 or a count method.34

Following Bevan and Estrin, we shall use an indicator of riskiness that can easily be accessed, not least by decision makers in multinational corporations.35 This risk rating is derived from an ex ante assessment of the government default risk rather than an ex post evaluation constructed by researchers. Credit ratings of country j originate from various issues of Institutional Investor,36 a biannually published journal. The Institutional Investor credit rating ranges from 0 (indicating countries with the lowest creditworthiness) to 100 (indicating the lowest likelihood of a country default risk).

Table 1 gives an overview of the variables used in the models, their explanations and the expected signs.

Table 1
Independent variables in the models
Variable Definition Reasons for inclusion Expected sign
GDPi GDP of the source country in current US$ A measure of the economic development and the capacity to supply of the source country +
GDPj GDP of the host country in current US$ Captures demand for goods and services and represents the market size hypothesis +
tradeij Imports in thousands of dollars*1000/GDPi, ratio Indicates the degree of international exposure; a measure of openness of the economy; most FDI is directed towards the traded goods sector +
ULCj Labour costs = Average wage in manufacturing (earnings per month in LUC)*12/GDP per capita (current LUC), ratio Evaluates alternative locations based on real costs -
distanceij Air distance between two capitals in km Captures the neighbouring effect -
riskj Credit ranking by Institutional Investor from 1 to 100 Captures a bundle of institutional, legal and political factors in the host county +

Note: LUC = Local unit of currency.

Source: Authors’ elaboration.

Empirical results

Regression analyses were carried out according to specification (1) and (2) as described above. Table 2 reports the results for analysing the determinants of FDI inward flows, and Table 3 lists the results for the determinants of FDI inward stock. Both specifications have been calculated with lagged and non-lagged independent variables.37

Table 2
Determinants of FDI inward flows to transition economies
FDIINij
(non-lagged)
FDIINij
(one year lag)
GDPi 1.54E-11** 1.73E-11**
(2.050643) (2.257254)
GDPj 7.00E-10*** 6.70E-10***
(11.42380) (11.42467)
tradej 4205.105*** 4124.553***
(8.352378) (8.062738)
riskj 1.618404 0.630274
(1.485636) (0.572850)
distanceij -0.032038*** -0.034238***
(-2.998130) (-3.170906)
ULCij -8.921538** -8.942268**
(-2.502777) (-2.443761)
Constant -15.03857 53.80475
(-0.222120) (0.784621)
No. of obs. 1531 1627
R2 0.150314 0.135000
F-Statistic 44.93405 42.13865

Note: The parentheses contain the t-statistic. * Significant at the 10% level; ** significant at the 5% level; *** significant at the 1% level.

Source: Authors’ elaboration.

Table 3
Determinants of FDI inward stock of transition economies
FDIISij
(non-lagged)
FDIISij
(one year lag)
GDPi 1.17E-10*** 1.58E-10***
(5.391693) (6.211955)
GDPj 1.30E-08*** 5.30E-09***
(26.25297) (18.49331)
tradej 27212.11*** 26559.82***
(18.89651) (15.65246)
riskj 1.001227 13.75647***
(0.423083) (5.157703)
distanceij -0.167910*** -0.229216***
(-5.815189) (-6.810226)
ULCij -1.989998 -4.760970***
(-1.265919) (-2.573524)
Constant -278.7477 -279.1800*
(-2.022213) (-1.750494)
No. of obs. 2254 2329
R2 0.379507 0.28536
F-Statistic 229.0521 154.5315

Note: The parentheses contain the t-statistic. * Significant at the 10% level; ** significant at the 5% level; *** significant at the 1% level.

Source: Authors’ elaboration.

Overall, both regressions show highly significant results. We reject the null hypothesis of joint parameter insignificance at the one per cent level.

The positive and significant coefficients for source and host country GDP and the negative and significant coefficient for distance indicate that FDI in CEECs is determined by gravity factors, i.e. FDI flows are attracted from relatively large economies to relatively large recipient economies, but the gains from foreign production activities diminish with distance from the source economy. We also find that unit labour costs exhibit a negative and significant coefficient, indicating that locations with relatively lower unit labour costs attract greater FDI flows, regardless of distance or host country size. Our finding that FDI is negatively affected by unit labour costs supports our expectation that foreign investors are cost sensitive.

The positive relationship between trade openness and FDI is also supported by our results. FDI and trade are complementary because host countries that have higher trading volumes with source countries also draw significantly more FDI.38

Somewhat surprisingly, FDI inflows to CEECs are not always influenced significantly by institutional factors, measured in terms of creditworthiness. While the variable risk and FDI are positively correlated in a bivariate analysis, risk becomes insignificant when the other variables are included in the regression. The coefficient is positive and significant only for FDI inward stock in the estimation that uses lagged explanatory variables.

Conclusion

In general, the results show that countries that are more successful in attracting FDI have growing (market) economies and low labour costs, and they exhibit trade openness. This finding is in line with other studies.39

Our expectation that a high risk of country default is a deterrent to foreign investment has not been fully confirmed. As we have shown above, low risk is not sufficient, and high risk is not necessarily a hindrance for FDI. Transition countries seem to attract FDI regardless of their assessed level of sovereign default risk. This could be because single large investment projects may still be deemed very attractive and because market access, especially for consumer goods, is highly valued. This finding should, however, by no means imply that efforts to achieve stable and reliable institutions may be dispensed with.

Positive economic development effects through FDI require diversified inward FDI flows within a stable market-oriented environment. Attracting market- or resource-seeking FDI, in combination with the low (labour) cost argument, might be reasonable, especially in an early phase of catching-up, but it cannot be regarded as a lasting and long-term strategy. Policy makers should aim at technologically attractive FDI at an early stage that will help create adequate physical and educational infrastructure.

The article was prepared within the framework of the Basic Research Program at the National Research University Higher School of Economics (HSE) and supported within the framework of the subsidy granted to the HSE by the Government of the Russian Federation for the implementation of the Global Competitiveness Program.

  • 1 European Bank for Reconstruction and Development: Transition Report, London 2002.
  • 2 For a discussion, see F. Di Mauro: The effects of economic integration on FDI flows: an empirical analysis and comparison with trade, Document paper No. 134, Brussels 1999, Centre for European Policy Studies; C.M. Buch, R.M. Kokta, D. Piazolo: Foreign direct investment in Europe: Is there redirection from the South to the East?, in: Journal of Comparative Economics, Vol. 31, 2003, pp. 94-109.
  • 3 United Nations Conference on Trade and Development: World Investment Report, New York and Geneva 2002.
  • 4 CEECs: Albania, Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Croatia, Hungary, Lithuania, Latvia, Poland, Romania, the Russian Federation, the Slovak Republic, Slovenia and Ukraine.
  • 5 High-income countries as a source of FDI are: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland and the United States.
  • 6 R. Grosse, L.J. Trevino: New Institutional Economics and FDI Location in Central and Eastern Europe, in: Management International Review, Vol. 45, No. 2, 2005, pp. 123-145; R. Narula, C. Bellak: EU enlargement and consequences for FDI assisted industrial develop-ment, in: Transnational Corporations, Vol. 18, No. 2, 2009, pp. 69-89.
  • 7 J. Bouoiyour: The Determining Factors of Foreign Direct Investment in Morocco, in: Saving and Development, Vol. 1, 2007, pp. 91-105.
  • 8 M. Duce: Definitions of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI): a methodological note, 2003, BIS Meeting of the CGFS Working Group; J.P. Walsh, J. Yu: Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment: A Sectoral and Institutional Approach, 2010, IMF Working Paper, International Monetary Fund, WP/10/187; E. Demirhan, M. Masca: Determinants of foreign direct investment flows to developing countries: a cross-sectional analysis, in: Prague Economic Papers, Vol. 4, 2008, pp. 356-369.
  • 9 E. Bessonova, K. Gonchar: Bypassing weak institutions in a large latecomer economy, in: Journal of Institutional Economics, Vol. 11, No. 4, pp. 847-874; R. Grosse, L. J. Trevino, op. cit.; A. Seric: Determinants of FDI location in Central and Eastern Europe (CEE), in: OECD Journal: General Papers, Vol. 2010, No. 2, 2011, pp. 77-90.
  • 10 J.H. Dunning, S.M. Lundan: Multinational enterprises and the global economy, 2nd edition, Cheltenham 2008, Elgar.
  • 11 United Nations Conference on Trade and Development: World Investment Report, New York and Geneva 1998.
  • 12 J.R. Markusen, A. Venables: Multinational Firms and the New Trade Theory, in: Journal of International Economics, Vol. 46, No. 2, 1998, pp. 183-203; J.R. Markusen, A. Venables: The Theory of Endowment, Intra-Industry, and Multinational Trade, in: Journal of International Economics, Vol. 52, No. 2, 2000, pp. 209-234.
  • 13 C.M. Buch et al., op. cit.; A. Bevan, S. Estrin: The determinants of foreign direct investment into European transition economies, in: Journal of Comparative Economics, Vol. 32, 2004, pp. 775-787.
  • 14 L. Artige, R. Nicolini: Evidence on the Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment: The Case of Three European Regions, Working paper 2006/07, 2006, Center of Research in Public Economics and Population Economics.
  • 15 A. Charkrabarti: The Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment: Sensitivity Analyses of Cross-Country Regressions, in: Kyklos, Vol. 54, No. 1, 2001, pp. 89-114.
  • 16 E. Demirhan, M. Masca, op. cit.
  • 17 E. Helpman: A simple theory of international trade with multinational corporations, in: Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 92, 1984, pp. 451-471.
  • 18 I.B. Kravis, R.E. Lipsey: Location of Overseas Production and Production for Exports by U.S. Multinational Firms, in: Journal of International Economics, Vol. 12, 1982, pp. 201-223; C.G. Culem: The Locational Determinants of Direct Investment among Industrialized Countries, in: European Economic Review, Vol. 32, 1988, pp. 885-904; S. Edwards: Capital Flows, Foreign Direct Investment, and Debt-Equity Swaps in Developing Countries, Working Paper No. 3497, 1990, NBER.
  • 19 A. Charkrabarti, op. cit.
  • 20 Overseas Development Institute: Foreign Direct Investment Flows to Low-Income Countries: A Review of the Evidence, Briefing Paper, September 1997.
  • 21 D.G. Goldsbrough: The Role of Foreign Direct Investment in the External Adjustment Process, in: Staff Papers, Vol. 26, 1979, pp. 725-754; R.S. Saunders: The Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment, in: Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 15, 1982, pp. 77-84; K. Flamm: The Volatility of Offshore Investment, in: Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 16, No. 3, 1984, pp. 231-248; F. Schneider, S.F. Bruno: Economic and Political Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment, in: World Development, Vol. 13, No. 2, 1985, pp. 161-175; C.G. Culem, op. cit.; A.F.M. Shamsuddin: Economic determinants of foreign direct investment in less-developing countries, in: The Pakistan Development Review, Vol. 33, No. 1, 1994, pp. 41-51; D. Holland, N. Pain: On the Road to the Market: The Prospects for Growth in Central Europe, London 2000, National Institute for Economic Research, mimeo; A. Bevan, S. Estrin, op. cit.
  • 22 A. Bevan, S. Estrin, op. cit.
  • 23 Ibid.; C. Martin, F.J. Velazquez: The determining factors of foreign direct investment in Spain and the rest of the OECD: Lessons for the CEECS, Discussion Paper No. 1637, London 1997, Centre for Economic Policy Research.
  • 24 A. Bevan, S. Estrin, op. cit.
  • 25 D. Loree, S.E. Guisinger: Policy and Non-Policy Determinants of U.S. Equity Foreign Direct Investment, in: Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 26, 1995, pp. 281-300.
  • 26 W.J. Henisz: The institutional environment for multinational investment, in: Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, Vol. 16, 2000, pp. 334-364.
  • 27 For the source and recipient countries, see footnotes 1 and 2. Some Eastern European countries, such as Bosnia and Herzegovina, Macedonia, Montenegro, Belarus, and Moldova, were excluded because they could skew the results due to too many missing data.
  • 28 A. Bevan, S. Estrin, op. cit.
  • 29 Ibid., E. Demirhan, M. Masca, op. cit.
  • 30 K.W. Jun, H. Singh: The determinants of foreign direct investment: new empirical evidence, in: Transatlantic Corporations, Vol. 5, 1996, pp. 67-106.
  • 31 L. Resmini: The determinants of foreign direct investment into the CEECs: new evidence from sectoral patterns, in: Economics of Transition, Vol. 8, 2001, pp. 665-689.
  • 32 A. Bevan, S. Estrin, K. Meyer: Foreign investment location and institutional development in transition economies, in: International Business Review, Vol. 13, 2004, pp. 43-64.
  • 33 D. Wheeler, A. Mody: International Investment Location Decisions: The Case for U.S. Firms, in: Journal of International Economics, Vol. 33, 1992, pp. 57-76.
  • 34 L. Resmini, op. cit.
  • 35 A. Bevan, S. Estrin, op. cit.
  • 36 Institutional Investor, Euromoney Institutional Investor, London.
  • 37 Only distance could not be included as a lagged variable.
  • 38 A. Bevan, S. Estrin, op. cit.
  • 39 Ibid.


DOI: 10.1007/s10272-016-0583-1